Two Ways to Calculate a Portfolio PE Ratio

Two Ways to Calculate a Portfolio PE Ratio 

Question:  The table below contains data on the market cap and the earnings for four high-tech firms.

Market Cap and Earnings for Four Tech Firms
Market Cap

($ B)

Earnings

($ B)

AAPL 892.16 46.65
MSFT 585.37 21.2
AMZN 475.37 1.92
TWTR 13.11 -0.44797

 

In this post, I am asking you to use two methods to calculate the PE ratio of this four-stock portfolio and to confirm that both methods provide the same answer.

Method One:

Calculate the PE ratio of this portfolio by taking the sum of the market cap numbers for the four stocks and dividing by the sum of the earnings of the four stocks.

Method Two:

Calculate the ratio of (market cap minus earnings) divided by market cap for the four stocks.

Calculate a weighted average of the values (MC-E)/MC for the four stocks with the ratio weighted by MC.  Give the name to this weighted average the letter f.

Calculate 1/(1-f).

Show that the PE ratio from method one is identical to 1/(1-f).

Analysis:

The straight forward way to calculate the PE ratio by taking the ratio of the sum of the market caps to the sum of the earnings is presented below.

Portfolio PE Ratio – Method One
Market Cap

($ B)

Earnings

($ B)

AAPL 892.16 46.65
MSFT 585.37 21.2
AMZN 475.37 1.92
TWTR 13.11 -0.44797
Total 1966.0 69.3 28.4

 

This four-firm portfolio has a PE ratio of 28.4.

The PE ration calculation for method two  is presented below.

 

Portfolio PE Ratio — Method Two
Market Cap Earnings (MC-E)/MC Weight
AAPL 892.16 46.65 0.9477 0.4538
MSFT 585.37 21.2 0.9638 0.2977
AMZN 475.37 1.92 0.9960 0.2418
TWTR 13.11 -0.44797 1.0342 0.0067
1966.01 1.0000
f 0.9647
1/(1-f) 28.4

 

The second method for calculating a PE ratio gives the same result as a the first – 28.4.

Implications:   The PE ratio of a portfolio can be expressed as function of the weighted average of the ratio of the difference between market cap and earnings of the firm to market cap of the firm.    This is a very useful result.

PE ratios of firms are frequently not useful.

First, the PE ratio can become very large when earnings are very small. This means it is misleading to look at a weighted average of PE ratios because one firm can have a a very large impact. In our current example, the PE ratio of Amazon is 248 and the weighted average PE ratio for the four stocks is  77.

Second, PE ratios have no economic meaning when earnings are negative.

The PE ratio of a firm with negative earnings would reduce the weighted average of PE ratios in a portfolio.  By contrast, (MC-E)/MC will be larger than 1 if E is less than 0.

A firm with slightly negative earnings would have a negative PE ratio with a larger absolute value than a firm with very large losses.  This ranking of firms is incorrect because larger losses should be associated with lower relative valuations.   By contrast, (MC-E)/MC will always rise when E falls.

By contrast, the ratio of the difference between market cap and earnings over market cap is inversely related to the valuation of a firm.   When earnings are negative this ratio is greater than one.   When earnings are zero the ratio equals one.   When earnings are very small the ratio approaches one and is not an outlier.  The ratio of the difference between the market cap and earnings to market cap is intuitively defined for all earnings and not impacted by outliers.

In my next post, I will show that statistical tests based on samples of the ratio of the difference between the market cap and earnings to market cap are more useful than statistical tests based on PE ratios.

 

Measuring Returns for Different Investment-Consumption Patterns

Measuring Returns for Different Investment-Consumption Patterns

Question:   An investment advisor tells his client to invest $1,000 per month in VFIAX (Vanguard S&P fund) for five years.   The person will then live off the proceeds in this fund for 36 consecutive months.

Calculate the return on assets from this investment/consumption plan for two different start dates – January 1, 2002 and January 1, 2003.

What is the NPV of investment returns from this investment strategy/ consumption plan on the same start dates?

What should investors who are planning to save for five years and spend for three years learn from this example?

Mutual funds and ETFs tend to advertise holding period returns based on specific purchase dates and specific sale dates.   These returns are based on the price of securities on two dates only.   What does the example presented here tell you about the usefulness of two-period return statistics reported by mutual funds?

Methodological Note:  The shares purchased each month are $1,000/PVFIAX where PVFIAX is the price of the ETF.   I sum over 60 months to get the total shares purchased, which I will denote TSHARES. The formula for cash inflow for the 36 months are (1/36)*TSHARE*PVFIAX.

The cash inflow/outflow column and the date column are inputted into the XIRR function in Excel to give the IRR of the inflows/outflows on these particular dates. The XNPV function gives net present value of the cash flows.

Analysis:

The value of VFIAX reached its pre financial crisis high in 10/2007 and reached its crisis trough in 02/2009.   Hindsight is 20/20 but it appears as though diversification prior to the downturn would have been beneficial.

What follows are return calculations for the two scenarios.

Results are in the table below.

Returns for Two Investment/Consumption Scenarios
Invest Period Consumption Period IRR NPV
2002/2006 2007/2009 12.04 $15,766
2003/2007 2008/2010 2.98*e-9 $801

Observations:

  • The person who stopped saving in December 2006 did fairly well despite the financial crisis.The IRR for this investor was 12.04 %.   The NPV of the investments was $15,766.   (NPV calculation assumes a5 percent cost of capital.) 
  • The person who stopped investing in December 2007 realized a return only slightly higher than 0 percent.The NPV of this person’s investment was around $800.

Discussion of Investment Strategy:

In my view, a 100 percent VFIAX strategy is unwise for an investor with this type of investment and consumption period.

How to fix this problem is a more difficult question.  It is important to note that the strategy of putting 100 percent of funds in VFIA for an investor with a start date of January 1 2009 or January 1, 2010 did quite well.

529 plans offer life-cycle funds that drift towards a more conservative investment as the person nears the date where he must spend money.   Lifecycle funds would have done reasonably well for both of the scenarios considered here.  However, the life-cycle approach creates miserable results when the market does poorly in the first few years of the investment period and then rebounds.

My view on how to solve this problem is evolving.  A 60/40 (stock/bond) portfolio would have done well in these time periods but I don’t believe that it will work in the next crash.  Interest rates are now very low and I expect in the next crisis bonds and stocks will crash together.   Perhaps allocating some resources into an inflation-indexed bond fund would help balance returns during the next crisis.

The trend in investment is toward investment in passively managed funds like the ones offered by Vanguard.    This is at best a partial solution.   Investors need help in allocating money across several passively managed funds.  This includes advice on initial allocations and reallocation over time.

I believe there is a need for an actively managed fund that invests exclusively in passively managed funds and reallocated assets across funds as market conditions change.

Note on traditional holding period statistics:  The value of VFIAX in January 2002 was 17.9.  In December of 2010 the value of VFIAX was 39.5.   The return for this 7.9 year  holding period was at 10.5%.

Holding Period Calculation
Jan-03 17.9
Dec-10 39.5
Holding Period in Years 7.92
ROR 10.5%

However a person who started investing in January 2003 and started spending in January 2008 earned squat!   

The mutual funds can legally and honestly report great eight-year or ten-year holding return but their clients aren’t doing particularly well.

Such a surprise!   

Expected Profit and Risk with Random Transaction Dates

Profit and risk when there are four random purchase dates and four random sale dates

Question:   In 2013 a person buys QQQ the high tech ETF) on one of four randomly selected dates determined by when the broker arranges a meeting.   I

The person who bought the QQQ shares in 2014 got fired in 2015.   As soon as the person was fired he realized he needed cash so he called his broker and said “SELL QQQ” The firing is a random event independent of the market and out of control of the person, which occurred on one of four dates.

The four potential purchase and four potential sales dates for the QQQ transactions are presented below.

Information on Potential Purchases and Sales of QQQ
Potential Purchase Date Purchase Price QQQ Quantity purchased $25,000/Price Potential Sale Date Sale Price
20-May-14 88.0 284.1 5-Jan-15 101.4
7-Jul-14 95.1 262.9 8-Aug-15 110.5
7-Aug-14 94.2 265.4 24-Aug-15 98.5
10-Sep-14 100.1 249.8 5-Nov-15 114.7

The person spends $25,000 on the purchase of QQQ in 2014 and sells all shares in 2015.

Assume no dividends are paid.

What are all possible profit outcomes from the purchase and sale of the QQQ securities?

What is the expected profit?

What is the variance of profit?

Analysis:  The number of share purchased is $25,000 divided by the purchase price; hence the purchase price determines the number of shares purchased.

Tabulation of Number of Shares Purchased
Potential Purchase Date Purchase Price QQQ Number of shares purchased
20-May-14 88.0 284.1
7-Jul-14 95.1 262.9
7-Aug-14 94.2 265.4
10-Sep-14 100.1 249.8

Revenue received after the sale is price at time of sale times the number of shares owned.

Profit after the sale is revenue minus the $25,000 initial investment.

There are four possible purchase dates and four possible sale dates.   The purchase and sale dates are independent so there are a total of 16 possible equally likely combinations of sale and purchase dates.   The probability of each purchase/sale combination is 0.0625 (0.25*0.25).

The profit calculation for the 16 purchase-sale combinations is presented in the table below.

Potential Profit Calculation for Four Purchase Dates and Four Sale Dates
Comb # Probability Purchase Date Sale Date Number of Shares Owned Sale Price Profit
1 0.0625 20-May-14 5-Jan-15 284.1 101.4 $3,807
2 0.0625 20-May-14 8-Aug-15 284.1 100.5 $3,552
3 0.0625 20-May-14 24-Aug-15 284.1 98.5 $2,984
4 0.0625 20-May-14 5-Nov-15 284.1 114.7 $7,586
5 0.0625 7-Jul-14 5-Jan-15 262.9 101.4 $1,656
6 0.0625 7-Jul-14 8-Aug-15 262.9 100.5 $1,420
7 0.0625 7-Jul-14 24-Aug-15 262.9 98.5 $894
8 0.0625 7-Jul-14 5-Nov-15 262.9 114.7 $5,152
9 0.0625 7-Aug-14 5-Jan-15 265.4 101.4 $1,911
10 0.0625 7-Aug-14 8-Aug-15 265.4 100.5 $1,672
11 0.0625 7-Aug-14 24-Aug-15 265.4 98.5 $1,141
12 0.0625 7-Aug-14 5-Nov-15 265.4 114.7 $5,441
13 0.0625 10-Sep-14 5-Jan-15 249.8 101.4 $325
14 0.0625 10-Sep-14 8-Aug-15 249.8 100.5 $100
15 0.0625 10-Sep-14 24-Aug-15 249.8 98.5 -$400
16 0.0625 10-Sep-14 5-Nov-15 249.8 114.7 $3,646
Min -$400
Max $7,586
Range $7,986

The minimum profit is -$400.   The maximum profit is $7,985.

The expected profit is obtained by taking the dot product or the sumproduct of the probability vector with the profit vector.   The variance was obtained from the computational formula.

Var (Profit) = E(profit2) – E(Profit)2

For a discussion of these calculations see the previous post.

http://dailymathproblem.blogspot.com/2015/11/expected-value-and-variance-of-share.html

The expected value and variance or profit from the purchase of QQQ on one of four dates in 2014 and the sale of QQQ on one of four dates in 2015 are presented below.

Expected Profit and Variance of Profit Calculations
E(PROFIT) 2555.4
E(PROFIT2) 11036765.0
E(PROFIT2)-E(PROFIT)2 4506556.2
E(PROFIT-E(PROFIT))2 4506556.2

Financial Discussion:

The purchaser of QQQ or any stock that buys randomly and is forced to sell because of random events unrelated to the market bears substantial risk compared to an investor with enough liquid assets who will not need to sell in an emergency.   Investors would be wise to consider the level of the market and their ability to hold through downturns prior to selling.  The experts say that stock market returns beat returns on other securities over the long haul.  But this investor was only able to hold for a year.

Outcomes could have been worse.   The broker put the investor in QQQ a relatively diversified ETF that focuses on tech stocks.  Had the broker put his client in one particular stock (say IBM) and the investor was forced to sell he would have realized a large loss.

A note on the difference between geometric and arithmetic averages

Question:  The table below has price data and daily return data for Vanguard fund VB.   Calculate the arithmetic and geometric averages of the daily return data.   Show that the geometric average accurately reflects the relationship between the initial and final stock price and the arithmetic average does not accurately explain this relationship.

Daily Price and Returns For Vanguard 

Fund VB

Date Adjusted Close Daily Return
7/1/16 115.480674
7/5/16 113.99773 0.987158509
7/6/16 114.744179 1.006547929
7/7/16 114.913373 1.001474532
7/8/16 117.202487 1.019920345
7/11/16 118.128084 1.007897418
7/12/16 119.451781 1.011205608
7/13/16 119.10344 0.997083836
7/14/16 119.262686 1.001337039
7/15/16 119.402023 1.00116832
7/18/16 119.63093 1.001917112
7/19/16 119.202965 0.996422622
7/20/16 119.959369 1.006345513
7/21/16 119.481646 0.996017627
7/22/16 120.297763 1.00683048
7/25/16 120.019083 0.997683415
7/26/16 120.616248 1.004975584
7/27/16 120.347522 0.997772058
7/28/16 120.536625 1.001571308
7/29/16 120.894921 1.002972507
8/1/16 120.735675 0.998682773
8/2/16 119.12335 0.986645828

Analysis:   The table below presents calculation of the two averages and the count of return days.  The product of the initial value of the ETF, the pertinent average and the count of return days is the estimate of the final value.   Estimates of final ETF value are calculated for both the arithmetic average and the geometric average and these estimates are compared to the actual value of the stock on the final day in the period.

Understanding The Difference Between Arithmetic Mean and Geometric Mean Returns
Statistic Value Note
Arithmetic Average of Daily Stock Change Ratio 1.001506208 Average function
Geometric Average of Daily Stock Change Ratio 1.001479966 Geomean function
Count of Return Days 21 Count Function
Estimate of final value based on arithmetic average 119.1889153 Initial Value x Arithmetic Return Average x Count Days
Estimate of final value based on geometric average 119.12335 Initial Value X Geometric Return Average x Count Days
Ending Value 119.12335 Copy from data table

There is another way to show that the daily return should be modeled with the geometric mean rather than arithmetic mean.  The average daily return of the stock is (FV/IV)(1/n) – 1 where FV is final value and IV is initial value and n is the number of market days in the period, which for this problem is 21.

Using this formula we find the daily average holding period return is 0.001479966.  Note that 1 minus the geometric mean of the daily stock price ratio is also 0.001479966.

The geometric mean gives us the correct holding period return.

How much house can a student borrower qualify for?

How much house can a student borrower qualify for?

This answer depends on the maturity of the student loan.

Situation:

Consider a person with a $100,000 student debt.

  • The person can either pay the debt back over a 10-year period or a 20-year period.
  • The student loan is this person’s only consumer debt.
  •  The person earns $80,000 per year.
  • The student loan interest rate is 7.0 percent.
  • The mortgage interest rate is 4.0 percent.
  • The mortgage term is 30 years.

Questions:

  • How much mortgage can the person qualify for if the person keeps the student loan at 10 years?
  • How much mortgage can the person qualify for if the person changes the student loan term to 20 years?
  • What is the increased cost of the student loan payments involved by switching from a 10-year to 20-year student loan?

Answer:   I developed a spreadsheet that calculates the maximum allowable mortgage this person can qualify for.

In order to qualify for a mortgage two conditions must hold.

  • Monthly mortgage payments must be less than 28% of income.
  • Monthly mortgage and consumer loan payments must be less than 38% of income.

The procedure used to calculate the allowable mortgage is as follows:

  • First, I calculate the maximum allowable mortgage payment based on zero consumer debt.   This value is 28 percent of monthly income.
  • Second, I calculate the maximum allowable mortgage payment consistent with mortgage payments and consumer debt payments equal to 38 percent of income.   This is done by backing out the student loan and allocating the rest to mortgage debt.
  • Third, I insert mortgage interest rate, term and payment info into the PV functions to get the mortgage amount
  • Fourth, The allowable mortgage is the minimum of the mortgage totals consistent with the two constraints.

The calculations for the two situations presented in this problem are presented in the table below

Mortgage Qualification Example for Borrower with Student Debt
row # Student Loan Information Note
1 Student loan Amount $100,000 $100,000 Assumption
2 Interest Rate 0.07 0.07 Assumption
3 Number of Payments 120 240 Assumption
4 Student Loan Payment $1,161 $775 From  PMT Function
Mortgage Information
5 Rate 0.035 0.035
6 Term 360 360
Income Assumption
7 Income $80,000 $80,000 Assumption
8 Constraint One:  Maximum monthly mortgage payment consistent with this income assumption $1,867 $1,867 28% of monthly income
9 Constraint Two:  Maximum monthly consumer and mortgage payments consistent with income $2,533 $2,533 38% of monthly income
10 Maximum mortgage consistent with constraint one. $415,697 $415,697 pv of mortgage rate number of periods, and pmt where mortgage rate and payments are assumptions baed on the market and product chosen and payment is max allowable given   income
11 Allowable mortgage payment consistent with constraint two given required student debt $1,372 $1,758 Row 9 minus Row 7
12 Max mortgage consistent with borrowing contraint two. $305,593 $391,505 Use PV function with rate and term set by market and product and payment the amount of mortgage payment after required consumer payments
13 Allowable mortgage debt $305,593 $391,505 Minimum of Row 10 and Row 12

 

An increase in the term of the student loan from 10 to 20 years increases the size of a mortgage a household can qualify for from $305,000 to $391,000.

Getting the extra mortgage is not cheap.  The increased student loan term causes total student loan payments to go from $139.000 to $186,000.

Concluding thoughts:  Most people who have $100,000 in student debt will have to refinance the student loan if they are going to buy a house.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Student debt and qualifying for a mortgage 

Student debt and qualifying for a mortgage 

Excel Topics:  PMT function and Spreadsheet design

Question:  A person graduates from college and graduate school with $100,000 in student debt.   The interest rate on a 10-year student loan is 5% per year.   The person wants to buy a house that costs $300,000 with a 90% LTV loan. The home mortgage interest rate is 4.5% on a 30 year FRM.

Assume that in order to qualify for the house the person must meet two conditions.

Constraint One:  The ratio of mortgage interest to income must be less than 0.28.

Constraint Two: The ratio of total interest (mortgage and non-mortgage) interest must be less than 0.38.

How much income does this person need to qualify for a loan on this house?

Why might student debt have a smaller impact on the purchase of a $700,000 home than the purchase of a $300,000 home.

Analysis:   The analysis for the $300,000 home is laid out in the table below.

Mortgage Qualification Example for Borrower with Student Debt
Note
Student loan Amount $100,000 $0 Assumption
Interest Rate 0.05 0.05 Assumption
Number of Payments 120 120 Assumption
Student Loan Payment $1,061 $0 From  PMT Function
House Amount $300,000 $300,000 Assumption
LTV 0.9 0.9 Assumption
Loan Amount $270,000 $270,000 LTV * House Amount
Intrerest Rate 0.045 0.045 Assumption
Number of Payments 360 360 Assumption
Mortgage Payment $1,368 $1,368 From PMT Function
Total Loan Payments $2,429 $1,368 Sum Payments
Monthly Income Constraint One $4,886 $4,886 Student Loan Payment divided by 0.28
Monthly Income Constraint Two $6,391 $3,600 Mortgate Payment Divided by 0.38
Required Monthly Income $6,391 $4,886 Max of income over both constraints
Required Annual Income $76,696 $58,631 12* Max Income

Observations Pertaining to the $300,000 home for a person with and without student loans

A person with no student debt could qualify for this mortgage with an annual income of $58,630.

The person with the student debt needs an annual income of $71,585.

The impact of student debt on purchases of a larger home:   The allowable mortgage is determined by two constraints one involving mortgage debt only and the other involving the sum of mortgage and consumer debt.   When the mortgage debt is very large, constraint one (the mortgage debt constraint) will be the binding constraint.

Download the student debt and mortgage qualification spreadsheet by clicking below:
Continue reading Student debt and qualifying for a mortgage 

Understanding the Four Percent Rule

Question:   Is the 4.0% rule an appropriate guideline for determining the amount of savings a retiree should spend each year?

Background on the 4.0% rule:  Under the four percent rule (as I understand it ) the retiree’s expenditure in her first year of retirement is four percent of wealth in certain accounts.  It is more difficult to apply the 4.0% rule to total household wealth because house equity, a major component of wealth is not liquid.  (The application of the 4.0% rule to total wealth including house equity would at some point require the sale of the home.)

Whether strict adherence to the 4.0% rule leads to a smooth, stable, and sustainable consumption pattern for the household does  not depend solely on average asset returns or average inflation.   The timing of returns and the timing of inflation are also important.

A sharp decrease in returns at  the beginning of retirement could lead to a relatively quick depletion of assets if not accompanied by a decrease in spending.  By contrast, a sharp increase in returns at the beginning of retirement could allow retirees to spend more than allowed or provide a bequest to heirs.

The four percent rule could prove inadequate for workers who are planning to retire in 2017 or 2018 for two reasons.   First, both nominal and real interest rates are very low.   Second, stock valuations are currently extremely high.  Portfolio returns will fall precipitously if interest rates rise and stock prices fall.

Illustrating the 4.0% rule:  The simulations of whether the four percent return will lead to a successful retirement rely on two assumptions — the rate of return on assets and the inflation rate. Our model assumes that the retiree starts spending four percent of assets at retirement and continues to spend at this level in real terms adjusted for inflation.   The output of the model is the number of years (if ever) before the retiree spends all retirement funds.

We consider four scenarios — (1) 2.00% returns and 3.0% inflation all years, (2) 4.0% returns and 3.0% inflation rate for all years, (3) a -20% return the first year followed by 2.0% returns and 3.0% inflation, and (4) -20% return the first year followed by 4.0% return and 3.0% inflation.

Note that scenario two is better than scenario one because returns are higher in the second scenario.

Scenario three is similar to scenario one except for the fact that the market collapses in the first year.

Similarly scenario four is similar to scenario two but for the first-year collapse in asset prices.

The table below presents the number of years it takes for the person to deplete all assets using the four percent rule.

Adequacy of resource for 4% rule under four scenarios
Shock Return Inflation Rate Year Balance goes to $0
None 2.00% 3.00% 23
None 4.00% 3.00% 30
-20% first year 2.00% 3.00% 19
-20% first year 4.00% 3.00% 23

One bad year of returns in the first year of retirement resulted in a 7 year reduction of years with assets in the high return situation (simulation two minus simulation four) and a reduction of four years of assets in the low-return scenario (simulation one minus simulation three.)

The number of years prior to total depletion of assets among the four scenarios ranges from 19 years (scenario three) to 30 years (scenario two.)

 

Concluding Thoughts:

I suspect that these calculations understate the financial risk associated with adherence to the 4.0% rule, in general and in the current economic and financial situation.

The bad scenarios presented here involve a first year of retirement where the portfolio falls by 20 percent.   The collapse could be larger or more last more than one year.

President Trump believes that the the situation in Korea is the calm before the storm.   The same could be said for our financial markets and our economy.

The market is peaking.   The financial advisors and experts want to keep you fully invested argue that the market can run upwards for at least a few more years.   The more reputable analysts acknowledge that the valuations are high.   Long term interest rates remain low but when they rise (and they eventually will rise) bond prices fall.  The simultaneous collapse of bond prices and the reduction in stock valuations could will eventually lead to large losses at the beginning of retirement for a cohort of workers.

Some analysts suggest that investors who use the 4.0% rule should maintain a larger portion of their portfolio in equites.  I disagree.  The worse case scenario for the 4.0% rule involving poor stock and bond returns in a period of inflation actually occurred during the 1970s when inflation rose and stocks fell.   Luckily retirees in the 1970s had traditional pension plans that were not tied to the market.

President Trump believes that the the situation in Korea is the calm before the storm.   The same could be said for our financial markets and our economy.   I don’t believe the current calm before the storm will last.

 

 

A House Equity and Mortgage Payoff Spreadsheet

A House Equity and Mortgage Payoff Spreadsheet:

Question:   A person buys a house and plans to either sell and move or pay off the mortgage in twelve years.

The person is considering taking out a 15-year or a 30-year fixed rate mortgage.

The assumptions on the home purchase, house equity growth, the cost of selling and moving, and the cost of funds for the payoff of the mortgage are presented in the table below.

Table One: Assumptions for 30-year vs 15-year FRM Comparison:

Label 30-year FRM 15-year FRM
Purchase Price of House $500,000 $500,000
Down payment percentage 0.9 0.9
Initial Loan Balance $450,000 $450,000
Mortgage Term 30 15
House appreciation rate 3.0% 3.0%
Mortgage Interest Rate 4.0% 3.3%
Years person owns house 12.00 12.00
Cost of selling and moving to a new home as % of house value 9.0% 9.0%
Tax Rate on Disbursements from 401(K) Plan 30.0% 30.0%

 

Create a spreadsheet that provides estimates of house equity after the sale and move or mortgage payoff amounts after twelve years when the house buyer uses a 30-year FRM and when the house buyer uses a 15-year FRM

Base your mortgage payoff calculation on the assumption that the source of funds for the mortgage payoff are fully taxed funds from a 401(k) plan.

Spreadsheet:

http://wp.me/a2WYXD-4i

 

 

Results:

The results for the comparison of the 15-year and 30-year FRM for the assumptions presented in table one are presented in Table 2.

Table Two: Results for the 30-year vs 15-year FRM Comparison:

 

30-year FRM 15-year FRM
House Equity after Selling and Moving Costs $318,303 $540,109
Forecasted Mortgage Payoff Amount -$472,025 -$155,160

 

Observations on the 30-year vs 15-year FRM comparison:

The person taking out the 15-year FRM mortgage has around $222,000 more in house equity at the end of the 12-year holding period.

The mortgage payoff calculation when funds are disbursed from a 401(k) plan includes tax on the disbursements.   Inclusive of the tax bill, the mortgage payoff amount is $317,000 higher for the buyer who uses the 30-year FRM than for the buyer who uses the 15-year FRM.

Other Applications for the House Equity or Mortgage Payoff Spreadsheet:

 Modify the mortgage payoff calculation to allow for a situation where funds for the mortgage payoff are obtained from three sources – (1) a savings account, (2) sales of common stock, and (3) disbursements from a 401(k) plan.   Treat tax rates as an endogenous variable in the new model.

Compare results for both mortgage types under the 90% LTV assumption to results under an 80% LTV assumption.

Run the model on 15-year and 30-year FRMs for holding periods ranging from 1 to 15 years.   How does the advantage of the 15-year FRM vary with holding period?

Authors Note:   This problem was discussed further in the post below.

Essay Nine: Retire Mortgage Debt or Accumulate in Your 401(k) Plan:

https://financememos.com/2015/10/09/essay-nine-retire-mortgage-debt-or-accumulate-in-your-401k-plan/

Essay nine points out that many financial advisors stress accumulation of wealth in 401(k) plans rather than mortgage balance reductions even when their clients are nearing retirement.  The major banks employing the same financial advisors issue mortgages and sponsor 401(k) plans.   As a result, the interests of the financial advisors and the interests of their clients are not automatically aligned.

This approach can backfire when stock markets underperform nearing retirement.

During working years. the tax code favors people with large mortgages and people who are contributing to their 401(k) plan.  However, after retirement the person who must disburse funds from a 401(k) plan often has a hefty tax bill.

Interestingly, most financial analysts advise their clients to add more to their 401(k) plan rather than pay off their mortgage.  More discussion of this problem can be found below.

Reduce Mortgage or Add to Your 401(k) Near Retirement?

 

Reduce Mortgage or Add to Your 401(k) Near Retirement?

Increasingly, many Americans nearing the end of their work life find they have a large mortgage and must choose between paying off the mortgage or contributing more funds to their 401(k) plan. A large number of financial advisors advise their clients to increase 401(k) contributions rather than pay off their mortgage.

http://www.forbes.com/sites/nancyanderson/2014/01/03/7-reasons-not-to-pay-off-your-mortgage-before-you-retire/

http://www.kiplinger.com/article/real-estate/T040-C000-S002-should-you-pay-off-your-mortgage-before-you-retire.html

http://www.washingtonpost.com/news/get-there/wp/2015/03/26/the-case-for-not-paying-off-your-mortgage-by-retirement/

http://www.foxbusiness.com/personal-finance/2014/06/18/maybe-shouldnt-pay-off-your-mortgage-before-retirement/

http://business.time.com/2013/05/28/the-new-retirement-why-you-dont-have-to-pay-off-your-mortgage/

http://online.wsj.com/ad/article/privatewealthretirement-mortgage

http://www.schwab.com/public/schwab/nn/articles/Should-You-Pay-Off-Your-Mortgage-Early-Before-You-Retire

http://www.principal.com/planningcenter/retirementplanning/nearingretirement/retirementnews/mortgagequestion.htm

My view is that it is essential for people nearing retirement to eliminate their mortgage debt even if this goal requires some reduction in 401(k) contributions.   I have two reasons for this view.   First, as noted and explained in the previous section 401(k) plans are not capable of mitigating the impact of market down turns at the end of a career or during retirement.   Intuitively, a person with no debt is much better able to withstand market downturns than a person with a mortgage.   The Wall Street analysts always say don’t sell on a panic the market will come back.   Well retirees with a large mortgage often have no choice but to sell.

Second, the financial risk considerations interact with another factor, the tax treatment of 401(k) plans. During working years mortgage interest and 401(k) contributions reduce income tax burdens.   During retirement a person with a large mortgage payment and most financial assets inside a 401(k) plan will pay more in tax than a person without a mortgage.

All disbursements from a 401(k) plan are fully taxed at the ordinary income tax rate.   A person with no mortgage disburses enough to cover discretionary expenses and taxes   A person with a mortgage must disburse enough to cover discretionary expenses, the mortgage and taxes.

The disbursement to cover the mortgage leads to additional taxes because all disbursement from the 401(k) plan is taxed. MOREOVER, THE DISBURSEMENT ON FUNDS USED TO COVER THE TAX ON THE 401(K) DISBURSEMENT IS ALSO TAXED.

Part of Social Security is taxed for people with income over a certain threshold. A quick way to find out if part of Social Security benefit is taxable is to compare your income to the threshold for your filing status — $25,000 for filing status single and $32,000 for filing status married.

http://www.irs.gov/uac/Newsroom/Are-Your-Social-Security-Benefits-Taxable

Higher disbursements from the 401(k) plan can increase your adjusted gross income beyond the threshold and increase the amount of the Social Security benefit subject to tax.   Of course any 401(k) disbursement used to pay the income tax is also taxed.

So let’s take a household with all financial assets in their 401(k) plan with a $30,000 annual mortgage.   This monthly mortgage is $2,500, not huge.   Let’s assume that the person has to pay around $1,000 more in tax on Social Security benefits because of the additional disbursement to pay down the mortgage. A first order approximation of the amount of additional tax needed because of the additional $31,000 disbursement is $31,000 x the marginal tax rate for the taxpayer.   For most filers the marginal tax rate would be around 25 percent in 2014.

So the taxpayer with the mortgage and the additional tax burden because of the additional 401(k) disbursement will probably disburse $39,000 more per year from their 401(k) plan.

This analysis puts a whole new wrinkle on the question how much money does one have to save in their 401(k) to have a secure retirement.   The answer is much more if you have not paid off your mortgage.

Note that the disbursement to cover the unpaid mortgage must occur whether the market falls or rises.

Many people who choose to add to their 401(k) plan rather than pay off their mortgage prior to retirement are going to have sell their home and downsize. Downsizing may make sense but most people don’t want to downsize until they are fairly old.

Some people who end up selling their home may choose to rent rather than buy a new home.   The main risk of choosing to rent throughout retirement is that home prices and rents may rise.   This exacerbates longevity risk.

Downsizing should be a choice not an outcome from a failed financial plan or worse the result of financial advisors putting their interests over your interests

Concluding thoughts on mortgage debt in retirement: An increasing number of households are retiring prior to their mortgage being entirely paid off. Surprisingly, the existence of a mortgage in retirement is often consistent with a financial plan developed by a financial planner.   Many financial analysts and planners advise their clients to increase savings in their 401(k) plan rather than retire their mortgage.

These financial planners are not being upfront with their clients.   Retirees with mortgage debt and all or most financial assets in a 401(k) plan are at the whim of the market and have a substantial tax obligation.   The advice that put people in this position is in my view a form of malpractice.

Appendix to Essay on Mortgage Debt and 401(k) Assets in Retirement

The issue of whether to pay off a mortgage or contribute to a 401(k) plan for an older worker is related to the issue of mortgage choice, especially for older homebuyers.   The following question addresses the interaction between mortgage choice and 401(k) investment strategy for an older worker.

Question:   A 50 year-old person is buying a house and must choose between a 15-year mortgage and a 30-year mortgage.   The mortgage choice will impact how much money the person can contribute to his or her 401(k) plan.

The person makes $80,000 per year. The initial mortgage balance is $400,000.   The person’s 401(k) balance at age 50 is $200,000. The 30-year FRM rate is 3.9 percent and the 15-year FRM rate is 3.1 percent.

Discuss the advantages and disadvantages of two strategies (1) taking the 30-year FRM and investing 15% of salary in the 401(k) plan and (2) taking the 15-year FRM and investing 5% of salary in the 401(k) plan.

Analysis:

Let’s start with a reiteration of mortgage choice issues a subject previously broached in essay four.

Observations and Thoughts on Mortgage Choice Issues:

  • The monthly payment on the 30-year FRM is nearly $900 less than the monthly payment on the 15-year FRM. The higher mortgage payment on the 15-year FRM will all else equal require the person who chooses the 15-year FRM to make a smaller 401(k) contribution than the person who chooses the 30-year FRM.
  • After 15 years the 15-year FRM is completely paid off.   The remaining loan balance on the 15-year FRM is around $257,000.
  • Note that gains from the quicker pay down on the 15-year mortgage are not dependent on market fluctuations.   The gain from debt reduction occurs regardless of whether the market is up or down and regardless of when bear or bull makers occur.
Analysis of 15-Year Versus 30-Year FRM
  30-Year 15-Year
Mortgage 0.039 0.031
Term 360 180
Loan Balance 400000 400000
Payment -$1,886 -$2,781
Future Value $256,799 $0.00

 

Observations and Thoughts on Two 401(k) Contribution Strategies:

As noted in essay eight, the final 401(k) balance after 15 years depends on both the rate of return of the market and the sequence of the returns in the market.   Outcomes are presented for two market scenarios.   The first involves 7% returns for the entire 15-year period.   The second involves 7% returns for 10 years followed by -4% returns for 5 years.

  • The difference in the final 401(k) balances (high contribution minus low contribution) under the 15-year bull market scenario is around $211,000.
  • The difference in the final 401(k) balance (high contribution minus low contribution) under the 10-year bull and 5-year bear scenario is around $131,000
Analysis of Different 401(K) Contribution Strategies
5% Contribution Rate 15% Contribution Rate Difference
7.0% Return for 15 Years $675,442 $886,752 $211,309
7.0% Return for 10 years followed by -4.0% return for 5 years $394,339 $525,090 $130,751

The initial balance in the 401(k) plan for both scenarios is $200,000.

 

Additional insights on the tradeoff between 401(k) contributions and mortgage retirement:

 

  • The 30-year mortgage/high 401(k) contribution strategy results in major tax savings during working years compare to the 15-year mortgage/low 401(k) strategy.   All mortgage interest is tax deductible and the 401(k) contribution is not taxed.
  • The 15-year mortgage/low 401(k) contribution strategy results in major tax savings during retirement compared to the 30-year mortgage/high 401(k) strategy.   The previous example in this section demonstrated exposures for the person with mortgage debt in retirement when the person is dependent on 401(k) disbursements.   Remember all disbursements from a conventional 401(k) plan including disbursement used to pay the mortgage and disbursements used to pay taxes are fully taxed at ordinary income rates.   By contrast, the money gained from paying off the mortgage and most capital gains on owner-occupied real estate is not taxed.
  • Financial risks associated with a bull market persist through retirement as long as the saver allocates 401(k) assets into equity.

 

 

Thoughts on the Health Care Reform Process

Thoughts on the Health Care Reform Process

David Bernstein

Bernstein.book1958@gmail.com

Republicans argue that the ACA has failed and want to repeal it and replace it with something different; although, there is little agreement among Republicans on what plan should replace the ACA.  Most Democrats appear to deny or minimize the existence of problems with the ACA.   Some sort of government option appears to be the only major ACA reform supported by Democrats.

My view of the situation is that while the Ryan plan would have left many Americans worse off it is possible to devise a plan that substantially improves upon the ACA.   The objective of this memo is to outline changes to the ACA that would reduce premiums and improve quality of health plans sold through the state exchanges created under the ACA.

This memo concentrates on four issues  — (1) the relative importance of employer-based insurance and state exchanges,   (2) rules and incentives concerning the impact of age on premiums and coverage on state exchanges,  (3) rules governing use of health savings accounts and high-deductible health plans, and (4) the treatment of extremely expensive catastrophic health care cases.

Analysis:

Issue One — Relative Importance of Employer-Based Insurance and State Exchanges:  Currently state exchanges are much smaller than the employer-based market.  There exists some evidence indicating that people who obtain their health insurance through state exchanges are less healthy than people with employer-based insurance.  Most people with employer-based insurance are better off than people with state exchange insurance because employers often pay a substantial share of premiums.  Policy makers need to consider subsidies and rules that encourage the growth of state-exchange marketplaces without making workers and families currently covered by employer-based insurance worse off.

Discussion:   Under current ACA rules, employers with more the 50 employees are required to offer health insurance to their employees or pay a fine.    The tax credit for people getting insurance on state exchanges is only available for people with household income less than 400 percent of the FPL.    The tax credit has led to some small firms dropping offers of employer-based insurance.  However, most working-age people and their dependents continue to obtain health insurance through their employer.

The Health Care plan offered by Paul Ryan and ultimately rejected by the Freedom caucus would have eliminated the employer mandate for large firms and would have expanded tax credits for the purchase of state exchange health insurance to people with income over 400 percent FPL.   These changes would have induced many firms to eliminate their offer of health insurance to their employees.

One could argue that health insurance should not be tied to employment and that independent state exchanges reduce burdens on businesses and expand state mobility.   Moreover, the expansion of state exchanges is needed to make these new markets financially viable.

However, employer-based insurance is financially attractive to many employees.   Employers typically pay 70 percent of the premiums on employer-based plans.   The employer contribution is not subject to income or Social Security tax.   The workers who lose employer coverage under the Ryan plan would become worse off financially.  Under the Ryan plan, many people currently obtaining health insurance through their employer would lose offers of employer-based coverage and some of these individuals would find coverage through state exchanges to be inadequate or unaffordable.

There is a need for financial and economic incentives that reduce employer-based insurance and increase the role of state exchange insurance.   However, it is important that this reform not make workers who currently have employer-based coverage worse off.

Suggestions:   There are several potential policies that might expand state exchanges and reduce the role of employer-based insurance.

 

  • Employers should be allowed to contribute for the purchase of health insurance on state exchanges.   These contributions would be an expense for the business but would not be taxable income to the employee. These tax-favored contributions would replace the tax preference resulting from employer-based insurance.

 

  • Subsidies for the purchase of health insurance on state exchanges would also be given to federal, state and city employees and retirees, people on COBRA plans and people on Trade Adjustment Assistance TAA plans.

 

  • Employees at small firms that do not contribute to health insurance on state exchanges would be eligible for a tax credit.    The tax credit could be equal to the minimum or average contribution required by large employers.

 

Note One:  The tax credit proposed here is likely to be lower than current tax credits and the one proposed under the Ryan plan because of other subsidies and features of the plan.  First, the tax credit proposed here will be linked to the cost of a plan with high cost sharing, as described in issue three rather than the current silver plan.  Second, the proposal detailed in issue four for a government funded catastrophic health insurance plan also reduces premiums and the required subsidy.

Note Two: I am concerned that the availability of a tax credit could induce some firms to choose to not contribute funds for the purchase of health insurance on state exchanges.   Whether this is an actual problem depends on the design of the tax credit and the rules governing contributions from the employer.   I need to think about this issue a bit more.

Concluding thought on the need to increase size of state-exchange markets:  If the suggestions presented here were enacted, all working-age people not on Medicaid or government insurance would purchase their health insurance through state exchanges.   The mandate for an employer contribution would be needed in order to limit costs associated with the tax credit.  However, in my view the mandated employer contribution is less burdensome than pure employment-based health insurance.

Issue Two: There are too few young adults enrolled in state exchanges.    Policy makers need to create incentives for increasing the number of young adults who obtain their health insurance through state exchanges.

Discussion:   There are two reasons for the shortage of young people insured through state exchanges.    One involves a stipulation of the ACA requiring insurance companies to keep young adults on their parent’s policy up to including age 26.   The other involves the allowable age-rating ratios under the ACA.

The ACA rule keeping young adults on their parent’s policy up to the age of 26 is one of the most popular provisions of the ACA.  It has resulted in a substantial decrease in the number of young adults who lack health insurance.    Most parents of young adults get their health insurance from their employer.   As a result, most young adults also get their parent’s employer-based insurance policy rather than through state exchanges.

The ACA requires that insurance premiums be based on the age of the insured individual.    The maximum allowable ratio of premiums old people to young people allowed under the law is 3 to 1.    The Ryan plan increased the ratio to 5 to 1.   A 5 to 1 ratio would leave insurance unaffordable to low-income older households.  A 3 to 1 ratio is unfair to young adults. The issue of changes in the allowable age-rated premium ratio is in many respects a zero-sum game

Suggested Changes: A first step towards increasing the number of young adults with health insurance through state exchanges would involve changing the age-rated premium ratio.   I am recommending a modest initial change from the current ratio of 3 to 1 to a new ratio of 3.5 to 1.

Research has shown that a low old to young age premium ratio is especially problematic when the deductible on health plans is very high.  The paper linked below (which I authored) found that more than 80 percent of people between the age of 23 and 32 with a high-deductible health plan receive less than $500 in payouts from their health plan.

Intergenerational Transfers and Insurance Policy Designs

http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/abs/10.1080/10920277.2008.10597522

This observation suggests that the issue of premium regulations is linked to the issue of the type of health care plan offered in the market.   Issue three below discusses questions involving differences in cost sharing arrangements.

There appears to be little support for changing the provision of the ACA that allows young adults to remain on their parents health plan because this change in health care law is responsible for a dramatic increase in the number of young adults with insurance coverage.   However, there may be some policy changes that could induce some young adults to move off their parent’s policy into one obtained in state exchanges.

It might be appropriate to apply a modest annual fee for young adults who remain on their parent’s policy.   Funds from this fee could be used to subsidize out-of-pocket expenses for low-income people covered by high cost-sharing plans.

Alternatively, it may be appropriate to give people who turn 24 an extra $2,000 tax credit for a health savings account contribution if and only if they obtain a health plan from state exchanges.

Issue Three: The combination of high-deductible health plans and health savings accounts are unsuitable for many young households with high debt, limited income, and low levels of liquid assets.  Alternative cost sharing arrangements should be considered.

Discussion:   There are two main advantages of high-deductible health plans.  First,

High-deductible health plans result in a substantial reduction in health insurance premiums.   The reduction in health insurance premiums stems from the fact that the insurance company makes no payouts, except for some preventive services, until after the deductible is met.   Second, as long as the total health expenditures remain under the deductible the insured individual has a strong incentive to economize on health expenditures.

Most of the academic literature on the benefits of high-deductible health plans and health savings accounts involves a discussion of the extent to which these plans reduce the utilization of health services.

The following study by a group of economist found that the use of high deductible health plans reduced spending on out-patient care and on pharmaceuticals.   There was no evidence of increased use of in-patient services or emergency room services.

NBER study on impact of high-deductible health plans on utilization of health services.

http://www.nber.org/papers/w21031

There is also substantial concern that high-deductible health plans can cause people to forego needed procedures and not purchase needed medicines.

There are several potential problems and unresolved issues with the expanded use of high-deductible health plans.

First, the people who benefit the most from health savings accounts are high-income individuals with higher marginal tax rates.  Some conservatives including Rand Paul have argued that all people should be allowed to contribute to a health savings account regardless of the type of health insurance plan they use.    Conservatives also tend to want higher limits on the amount that people are allowed to contribute to health savings accounts.    This approach provides larger subsidies to people who already have comprehensive coverage.

Second, some households will only be able to fund health savings accounts by reducing contributions to their 401(k) plans. This change has little or no impact on savings and wealth accumulation.  It is similar to rearranging the deck chairs on the Titanic.

Third, as noted in my article intergenerational Transfers and Insurance Policy Design an estimated 80 percent of young adults will receive less than $500 in benefits from health savings accounts.  The low potential payout for most young healthy adults will result in many young adults foregoing health insurance if a high deductible plan is the only affordable option.

Fourth, higher deductible health plans would be more effective to lower-income households if they were coupled with subsidies for out-of-pocket expenses.   The ACA does provide subsidies for out-of-pocket expenses for low-income households.   Congress did not appropriate funds specifically for this subsidy.   The Obama Administration reallocated funds for this program but House Republicans initiated a legal challenge to this subsidy.   Courts are still considering this issue.

Fifth, increased cost sharing creates an incentive to forego needed procedures and/or to not take certain medicines.   These decisions could have adverse health consequences.

Suggested Changes:  Two suggested changes to the rules governing health savings accounts and high-deductible health plans should be considered.

First, low-income holders of qualified high-cost sharing plans should be given subsidies for some out-of-pocket expenses.  It may be desirable to end the litigation on out-of-pocket subsidies by agreeing to fund subsidies only for people with high-deductible or high cost-sharing health plans.

Second, policymakers should allow people with a high coinsurance rate plan to contribute to a health savings account even if the plan has a modest deductible.

The low-deductible health plan with a high coinsurance rate may actually have a higher impact on health care utilization than a high deductible health plan.   Consider two plans both with a $7,350 out-of-pocket limit.   The first plan has a $7,350 deductible and no cost sharing once the deductible is met.   The second plan has a $0 deductible and a 50 percent coinsurance rate until the $7,350 maximum allowable out-of-pocket limit is met.  Under the first health plan there is not more cost sharing once total health expenditures reach $7,350.   Under the second health plan cost sharing will continue until total health expenses reaches $14,700.

I suspect that wealth accumulated in a health savings account linked to a high cost-sharing plan will be higher than wealth accumulated in a health savings account linked to a high-deductible plan.   (I believe I could provide evidence supporting this hypothesis using MEPS data and a simple simulation model.)

Issue Four: Around 5 percent of the United States Population accounts for roughly half of health care spending in the United States.

AHRQ Statistical Brief  497: Concentration of Health Expenditures in the U.S. Civilian Noninstitutionalized Population, 2014 https://meps.ahrq.gov/data_files/publications/st497/stat497.pdf

The share of health care expenditures in a relatively few expensive patients is even higher for children and the working-age population

Health care expenditures across age groups:

http://www.dailymathproblem.com/2017/02/health-care-expenditure-patterns-across.html

The government could provide catastrophic health care coverage for all expenditures or a proportion of expenditures above a specific limit.  A universal catastrophic health insurance plan would reduce premiums on private insurance.

Discussion:   Prior to the ACA many health insurance plans had annual or lifetime limits.   Often people with health expenditures that exceeded the limits on the health care plans were unable to obtain additional health services.  The recently withdrawn Ryan health care plan retained the ACA prohibitions on caps on health care expenditures.

A new Freedom caucus version of an ACA repeal bill may very well allow insurance companies to impose annual or lifetime caps on expenditures.   This bill is also likely to include high-risk pools that could cover some people denied coverage because of the expenditure caps.   Past versions of high-risk pools had limited funds and covered only a small share of the uninsured.

The ACA included a limited reinsurance option that was designed to reduce incentives for insurance companies to avoid high-risk options.  This option was stopped when Republicans refused to fund the program.   Some states including Minnesota have thought about including a reinsurance procedure in their state exchanges.

http://milawyersweekly.com/news/2017/03/22/how-reinsurance-may-help-health-insurers/

Suggested Changes:  Create a program where the government will pay or all part of catastrophic health expenses above a certain limit.  For example the new government funded catastrophic health plan might pay for 80 percent of all health care expenses over $60,000 per year.  The individuals would continue to pay for all out-of-pocket expanses.   The private insurance company would no longer have to pay for expenses covered by the new catastrophic health plan.

Note One:  The new government funded reinsurance plan reduces premiums drastically for the new standard plan.   The higher deductibles or cost sharing also reduces premiums.  The lower premium allows the government to substantially reduce tax credits helping lower-income households afford premiums.   The cost of the reinsurance subsidy may be partially or even entirely offset by reductions in the tax subsidy depending on the details of the reinsurance program and the details of the new tax subsidy.

Note Two:  A replacement to the ACA that allows for insurance companies to impose caps on expenditures would lead to the death of some people once caps are reached.   It appears hard to fix this problem without some sort of government program.

Note Three:  One way to create a universal catastrophic health plan is to allow for automatic eligibility into Medicaid or Medicare for people with health expenditures that exceed a cap.   A second way might involve government purchasing a private catastrophic health plan with some private insurance company or consortium.   (This would be one huge contract.)

Note Four:  A universal catastrophic health plan would have a large impact on premiums and the reinsurer would only need to make payouts to a relatively few individuals.   I need to update my work on reinsurance, which was conducted prior to the passage of the ACA.

Geneva Paper on Reinsurance and Health Insurance in the United States:

https://www.jstor.org/stable/41953098?seq=1#page_scan_tab_contents

Concluding Remarks:

Here is the current situation.   The ACA has non-trivial flaws that need to be fixed.   The Republicans have done and continue to do everything they can to make sure the ACA fails. The Ryan bill would have led to the unraveling of employer-based health insurance and many people currently covered by employer-based polices or receiving tax credits on state exchanges would have been unable to afford health insurance under Ryan’s proposal.  The only Democratic plans put forward involve government options or single-payer plans, proposals that are not viable in the current political environment.   The Freedom caucus opposes any plan with a new entitlement even if the plan actually reduces the role of government in the health care system

Many of the recommendations discussed in this essay including the expansion of state exchanges, modification of age-rated premium formula, and changes rules governing health savings accounts are based on conservative principles.    The plan that I am outlining here  also contains a very large new government entitlement – universal catastrophic coverage for all U.S. citizens.   The new entitlement allows insurance companies to cap health annual expenditures.  This provision reduces premiums on private insurance and tax subsidies.

It is hard to see how issues related to the most expensive health care cases can be mitigated without some government involvement.   Even though this proposal contains a new entitlement this proposal should reduce total government involvement in the health care sector.  It is my hope a bipartisan group of Senators and Representatives will get behind a specific plan based on this analysis.